CBDC and Monetary Policy
Staff Analytical Note 2020-4
(English)
February 2020
Central banks and academics are discussing the possibility of central bank issuance of a digital currency. Many arguments exist for and against issuing a CBDC. This note discusses the two most important arguments from the perspective of the monetary policy objective of price stability. In the next two sections, we state each argument and discuss the corresponding caveats and implications for the form of a CBDC. Throughout this note, we assume that the CBDC is universally accessible, but we impose no assumptions on transaction limits.
During recessions, central banks normally reduce short-term interest rates to stimulate aggregate investment and consumption. When interest rates are close to the ELB, this policy is less effective because individuals can hold cash to avoid negative interest rates. This problem could be solved by restricting cash withdrawals and deposits, eliminating large-denomination notes or eliminating cash altogether. However, it may be more desirable to replace cash with an interest-bearing CBDC if, from a public policy perspective, there is a preference for a government-issued retail means of payment.
An interest-bearing CBDC could reduce the opportunity cost agents bear when holding means of payment. It would do this by allowing more flexible transfer schemes, where interest rates can be conditional on balances—for example, if agents held high money balances, they would be subject to a different interest rate than if they held low money balances. This could induce agents to maintain an efficient level of liquidity.1
A CBDC could influence the market for deposits. If CBDC and bank deposits were close substitutes, then a CBDC with a non-zero interest rate could provide a floor for deposit rates. Even if the CBDC were not widely used, the CBDC rate could influence the deposit market by offering depositors an outside option, making the deposit market more competitive.2 Interest rates on CBDC deposits could be an additional monetary policy tool that would need to be set consistently with other policy rates. In this way, deposit rates would be more closely linked to the CBDC and other policy rates, improving the transmission of monetary policy.
To realize these benefits, a CBDC would have to be designed to bear interest, both negative and positive. An account-based system may be preferable to a token-based system. This is because an account-based system allows for the policy interest rate to be time-varying and contingent on the balance held.
There are few quantitative estimates of the benefits of breaking below the ELB. Even if the benefits were large, other policies exist that could help break below the ELB without introducing a CBDC. One suggestion is to use a time-varying deposit fee on physical currency between private banks and the central bank (Agarwal and Kimball 2015). This would allow the central bank to create an exchange rate between physical currency and bank deposits, which would help implement a negative interest rate policy.
Likewise, estimates of the long-run benefits of a more flexible monetary policy are limited, and they range widely. We are aware of only two papers that study this issue:
Removing cash from the economy or restricting its holdings could have several immediate implications:
Further, “eliminating [cash] a core symbol of the monetary regime could disrupt common social conventions for using money, possibly in unexpected ways” (Rogoff 2017).
An additional challenge is that removing cash or restricting its holdings would be a necessary but not sufficient condition to potentially realize the benefit of breaking below the ELB during downturns. In fact, individuals would likely seek alternatives to a CBDC precisely during periods when central banks are pursuing negative interest rates. Alternatives could include foreign currencies or private cryptocurrencies, increasing the risk of their widespread adoption. This would ultimately reduce the effectiveness of monetary policy because these alternatives are not denominated in the domestic unit of account.
Lastly and importantly, little is known about how a CBDC would affect the current channels of transmission of monetary policy or whether new ones would emerge. For example, interest on a CBDC may be a more direct policy instrument because it does not need to be passed through to the economy by the financial sector. Further analysis is needed.4
The widespread adoption of alternative means of payment not denominated in the domestic currency would weaken the transmission of monetary policy because the central bank would have influence on a smaller portion of the economy. This consideration is particularly important if the suppliers of the alternative means of payment have interests that are not in line with the objectives of the central bank (Davoodalhosseini and Rivadeneyra 2018).5 In such a case, the central bank may be forced to respond to the policy of the supplier of alternative means of payment. This could increase the constraints and reduce the effectiveness of central bank monetary policy (Zhu and Hendry 2019). A CBDC, if it is appropriately designed, could counter the adoption of alternative means of payment.
The wide adoption of new means of payment denominated in the domestic currency would not threaten the central bank’s ability to implement monetary policy—even if this adoption were accompanied by a decline in the demand for cash. In fact, currently:
With or without cash in circulation, monetary policy can be implemented as long as payment providers demand the settlement asset controlled by the central bank.
It is unlikely that a scenario of widespread adoption of an alternative means of payment not denominated in the domestic currency will materialize in the near future. For it to happen, there would have to be a growing demand for certain features in means of payment that traditional instruments cannot provide. But at this moment, it is unclear what these features are or whether demand would be strong enough to drive agents to adopt an alternative means of payment not denominated in the domestic currency. One potential indicator of this scenario would be if commercial banks were to start taking deposits in large scale of such means of payment.
Issuing a CBDC, in practice, would be unlikely to help the central bank improve the effectiveness of monetary policy. One difficulty is that in order for a central bank to realize any potential monetary policy benefits, the CBDC would have to be able to bear interest (positive or negative) and cash would have to be removed or have its use restricted. In addition, the magnitude of these benefits, which are obtained from breaking the ELB in the short run and reducing the opportunity cost of holding liquidity in the long run, is still unclear and needs to be further explored. Finally, issuing a CBDC may not be the only way for a central bank to realize these benefits: for example, a central bank may be able to break the ELB under the current monetary system by charging a time-varying fee on cash deposits.
Bank of Canada staff analytical notes are short articles that focus on topical issues relevant to the current economic and financial context, produced independently from the Bank’s Governing Council. This work may support or challenge prevailing policy orthodoxy. Therefore, the views expressed in this note are solely those of the authors and may differ from official Bank of Canada views. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Bank.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.34989/san-2020-4
We use cookies to help us keep improving this website.